2(2)2014
Andrzej Bolesta
The East
Asian industrial policy: a critical analysis of the developmental state
Polityka przemysłowa państw
Azji Wschodniej: analiza krytyczna developmental state
Streszczenie
Współcześnie,
gdy zdyskredytowana doktryna neoliberalna przestała pełnić funkcję dominującego
wzorca polityki ekonomicznej oraz modelu systemowego, być może nadszedł moment
wielkiego powrotu polityki przemysłowej, rozumianej jako interwencje państwa
mające za cel stymulowanie rozwoju. W II połowie XX w. to
właśnie polityka przemysłowa prowadzona w państwach Azji Wschodniej przyniosła
najbardziej spektakularny rozwój. W literaturze przedmiotu sukces ten - zwany
wschodnioazjatyckim cudem - wyjaśniany jest na gruncie koncepcji developmental state (państwa rozwojowego, czy też
prorozwojowego).
W niniejszym
artykule Autor omawia główne kierunki polityki przemysłowej państw Azji
Wschodniej. Stawia też pytanie, czy takie podejście może być stosowane
współcześnie. Wymaga to wyjaśnienia, dlaczego polityka przemysłowa zyskuje na
popularności. Następnie Autor omawia dzieje powstania pojęcia państwa
rozwojowego, aby przejść do analizy najważniejszych jego elementów, tj. przede
wszystkim strategii naśladownictwa i innowacji, wybierania gałęzi przemysłu, w
które należy inwestować, polityki handlowej oraz wykorzystania subsydiów. W
konkluzji stwierdza, że chociaż koncepcja developmental state uznawana jest za zjawisko historyczne, to zasady, którymi kierowały się
państwa Azji Wschodniej w swojej polityce przemysłowej, nadal mogą być z
powodzeniem stosowane w innych częściach świata.
Słowa
kluczowe: rozwój gospodarczy, neoliberalizm, polityka przemysłowa, developmental state
The East Asian industrial policy: a critical analysis of the
developmental state
Abstract
In the times of discrediting neo-liberalism as the preferred
guiding doctrine in economic policy and systemic arrangements, the industrial
policy, understood as a set of state interventions to supervise the process of
developmental advancements, may come back to the fore as a favoured instrument.
It is the East Asian industrial policy which brought by far the most
spectacular developmental results in the second half of the twentieth century.
In the scholarly literature on the so-called East Asian miracle, this success
is explained by the concept of the developmental state.
This paper examines the main threads of the East Asian industrial
policy and tackles the issue of its contemporary applicability. It starts with
the explanation as to why industrial policy as such is becoming more popular.
It then examines the history of the formation of the concept of the
developmental state. It analyses its most important elements, mainly, the
strategy of imitating and innovating, the targeting of industrial sectors for
development, the trade policy and the utilisation of subsidies. In conclusion,
it is claimed that the provisions of the East Asian industrial policy may well
be employed contemporarily, despite the fact that the concept of developmental
state is primarily seen as a historical phenomenon.
Keywords: economic
development, neoliberalism, industrial policy
The crisis
and the alternative
Most of the
very recent economics related literature deals with the causes and consequences
of the global financial crisis 2008/2009[1].
A financial crisis is, as it seems, an inevitable element of the socio-economic
landscape of the contemporary world. Only in the last two decades there have
been several, for example, the 1997 financial crisis, which extensively
affected the economies of East Asia[2].
However, the recent financial crisis in some industrial nations, which became a
global economic crisis[3]
dubbed the Great Recession[4],
has been particularly painful, to the extent that it has often been compared
with the Great Depression of 1930. Various aspects and different stages of this
crisis have been given attention in numerous analyses. In its extensive
650-page report entitled Wall Street and the Financial Crisis: The Anatomy of a Financial
Collapse[5],
the US Senate cites regulatory failures as one of the reasons for the global
economic crisis. A lack of regulation explicitly and inadequate state
supervision implicitly are blamed for the havoc. Therefore, The Stiglitz
Report suggests the restoration of the state as the appropriate
regulator. It emphasises that ‘the crisis has exposed fundamental problems, not
only in national regulatory systems affecting finance, competition and
corporate governance, but also in the international institutions and arrangements
created to ensure financial and economic stability[6].
Many call for more explicit state interventionism. Scott states that ‘the
essential lesson of the last 30 years is that self - regulation of capitalism
is an ideological fig leaf that hides a superficial understanding of a system
that requires the coercive powers of government to restrain the competitive
urges of many of its leading players’[7].
Griffith-Jones et al. declare that it is time for “a visible hand”
in the market[8].
Giddens calls outright for the return of some sort of planning[9].
Chang underlines that the government needs to become bigger and more active’[10],
especially in developing countries, who are particularly disadvantaged, as far
as the effects of economic crises are concerned.
This brings
us to the question of possible development models, which would perhaps employ
the above mentioned principles and could effectively contribute to the
narrowing of the developmental gap between the high income economies and those
underdeveloped countries who hold the ambition to catch up. As we witness the
collapse of the neo-liberal doctrine as allegedly the universal panacea for persistent
underdevelopment, inevitably, the concept of the developmental state (DS) is
resurfacing as the historically most convincing empirical example.
The concept
is widely believed to be the conceptual background of state policies and state
institutional arrangements, leading to the unprecedented developmental
achievements among the so-called late developers of the Asian continent.
Countries such as Japan, Korea and Taiwan became developed nations within a
short period of time in the second half of the twentieth century. Especially
remarkable is the case of Korea, who’s GDP per capita in the 1950 s was
comparable to some impoverished post-colonial states in sub-Saharan Africa and
now it is a modern, high income economy. Nonetheless, the concept is often
portrayed as only a historically justifiable phenomenon which cannot relate to
contemporary conditions.
This paper
thoroughly examines the principles of the developmental state. It starts with
some historical background. It then proceeds with the examination of the
perceptions concerning East Asian industrial policies. It subsequently analyses
the DS concept by examining the industrial development through learning and
innovating and through sectoral targeting. It also describes the trade-related
policies and subsidies as financial sector-related interventions into the
market. The examinations compare the two largest DS economies; Japan and
(South) Korea, during their high growth periods[11].
Finally, it considers the models contemporary applicability.
It is
sometimes forgotten that the first meaningful criticism of Adam Smiths
classical economy’s theory of natural liberty did not come from Karl Marx. In
the first half of the nineteenth century, a German economist Friedrich List in
his study entitled The National System of Political Economy suggested
that Smith’s ideas would bring benefits to more affluent countries and leave
the less developed vulnerable, thus increasing the inter-country developmental
gap. His perception was influenced by Alexander Hamilton’s American school[12],
developed by the president of the United States, John Quincy Adams and senator
Henry Clay into the American system - an economic plan to support the US
domestic industries development by providing the necessary physical and
financial infrastructure, as well as by protecting them from foreign
competitors through tariff barriers. Hamilton, the first US Secretary of
Treasury, believed that those state interventions and protectionist measures
are necessary for overall socio-economic development.
The second
half of the nineteenth century was marked by the enforcement of the Listian
political economy into the systemic arrangements in continental Western Europe
and thus by creation of what perhaps can be seen as initial institutional
fundamentals for what would later become a developmental state. Its origins can
be traced from the institutional arrangements of Bismarck’s Prussia and the
Meiji restoration in Japan[13].
This model denied the capitalist class the dominant role in development,
entrusting the guiding of the process of socio-economic development to the
state. The state elite, supported by effective state bureaucracy, would guide
the process of the industrialisation of national economies. It was consistent,
to some extent, with the perception prevalent after the Great Depression until
the late 1970 s and motivated by the Keynesian theory, that the role of the
state or the public sector is crucial in the developmental endeavour,
especially among underdeveloped countries.
In the mid
twentieth century, when Western countries, comprising predominantly of Western
Europe and North America, distanced the rest of the world in terms of the level
of development and continued to rely on what evolved from the model of
capitalist development and the Prussian interventionist state, and, at the same
time, Eastern Europe was coerced into adopting the state-command economic
system, the so-called developing countries, many of which were emerging from
colonialism, were in desperate need for a developmental model to enable
significantly better developmental dynamics in order to establish a sound
trajectory of “catching up”.
By the end of
the twentieth century, among the most successful late developers were those
countries who became developmental states, i.e. South Korea, Taiwan and
Singapore, as well as Japan - considered a prime example of the developmental
state model, despite a rather “early” start to “late development”.
The concept
of the developmental state is often believed to be the institutional
explanation for the East Asian industrialisation. Ha-Joon Chang, however,
points out that there is no unambiguous definition of the industrial policy
(IP) and that the term is often used in reference to too narrow a spectrum of
economic activity, namely, the state subsidies policy, or too broad a spectrum,
namely, any economic
Andrzej Bolesta
activity
related to industry[14].
Indeed, Cimoli, Dosi and Stiglitz
claim that industrial policy comprises policies affecting “infant industry”
support of various kinds, but also trade policies, science and technology
policies, public procurement, policies affecting foreign direct investments,
intellectual property rights, and the allocation of financial resources. [They
conclude that] industrial policies, in this broad sense, come together with
processes of “institutional engineering” shaping the very nature of the
economic actors, the market mechanisms and rules under which they operate, and
the boundaries between what is governed by market interactions, and what is
not’[15].
Rodrik sees industrial policies as ‘policies that stimulate specific economic
activities and promote structural change, thus, are not [exclusively] about
industry per se[16].
However, for Lindbeck those policies do not involve monetary and fiscal
measures[17].
For Haggard (2004, p.64) industrial policies comprise selective interventions
designed to influence the allocation of resources among different activities’[18].
‘When we talk about “industrial policy”, the majority of us do not mean any
policy that affects industry [but] “selective industrial policy” or “targeting”
- namely, a policy that deliberately favours particular industries over others,
against market signals, usually to enhance efficiency and promote productivity
growth’[19].
“Against market signals” is the cause of the debate between proponents and
opponents of the applicability of industrial policy as a developmental tool, in
other words, whether industrial policy actually matters. ‘The traditional rationale
for selective industrial policy (i.e. policies intended to promote specific
industries as against general policies to promote industrialisation) has been
made in terms of “market failures” that arise when competitive markets either
do not exist or are incomplete, in situations, for example, when there are
information asymmetries, scale economies, or externalities’[20].
Its opponents question the correlation between the policies and the dynamics of
economic growth[21].
Their objections concern the effectiveness of governments addressing the market
imperfections and constructing adequate counter policies, and the governments’
ability to eliminate rent seeking and corruption associated with industrial
policy[22].
Its proponents claim that ‘industrial policies [are] intrinsic fundamental
ingredients of all development processes’[23],
despite their shortcomings. Graham claims that industrial policy opponents
misread the history and that industrial policy has always been present in some
forms, even in the United States during Reagan’s deregulation period[24].
There is a
plethora of literature on industrial policy, its features, history and
applicability. Initially, the justification for industrial policy would come
from the perception that market forces are incapable of structural change of
the economy necessary in the process of socio-economic development.
‘Development is fundamentally about the structural change: it involves
producing new goods with new technologies and transferring resources from
traditional activities to new ones. [...] Poor countries remain poor because
markets do not work as well as they could to foster the structural
transformation that is needed’[25].
Therefore ‘there was broad consensus around the basic assumption that
development required [a] non-marginal change that market forces alone could not
generate’[26].
Chang points out that the history of rapid development of currently affluent
states is dotted with interventionist practices framed within the industrial
policy, since the eighteenth century[27].
However, a “neoclassical backlash” resulted in the industrial policy being
questioned as to its developmental role, as its application was allegedly
linked to poor economic performance. Although neo-liberal economic doctrine is
in retreat, ‘the context for the design of industrial policy has profoundly
changed as a result of new rules governing international trade, the rise of
global value chains and marketing networks, and other aspects of globalisation[28].
Most of the
recent scholarly literature on industrial policy is associated with the rapid
development of East Asian states. Socio-economic regional advancements of
Japan, Korea and Taiwan have been closely linked not merely in the context of
wild- geese-flying pattern[29],
but also due to the long-term political and economic interaction, particularly
intense during the Japanese colonialism[30].
As far as industrialisation is concerned, the East Asian states are often
portrayed against Latin American countries, the latter believed to be the first
developing nations to industrialise. The main difference between the two
regions is usually framed within the debate on outward (i.e. export driven) and
inward (i.e. domestic consumption driven) industrialisation in East Asia and
Latin America, respectively. However, according to Chang, the East Asian type
of industrial policy involves ‘a lot more than handing out subsidies and
providing trade protectionism (e.g., tariffs, import bans, quotas, domestic
regulations at least partially intended to curb imports). According to him,
industrial policy measures in East Asia included:
-
coordination of complementary investments (the so-called Big Push)
and competing investments through entry regulation, “investment cartels”, and
(in declining industries) negotiated capacity cuts;
-
policies to ensure scale economies (e.g., licensing conditional
upon production scale, emphasis on the infant industries starting to export
from early on, state- mediated mergers and acquisitions);
-
regulation on technology imports (e.g., screening for overly
obsolete technologies, cap on technology licensing royalties), when the state
acts as a venture capitalist and an incubator for high-tech firms;
-
regulation on foreign direct investment (e.g., entry and ownership
restrictions, local contents requirement, technology transfer requirements,
export requirements);
-
export promotion (e.g., export subsidies, export loan guarantees,
marketing help from the state trading agency);
-
government allocation of foreign exchanges, with top priority
going to capital goods imports (especially for export industries) and the
bottom priority to luxury consumption good imports[31].
In his “classic” work on Japanese industrialisation, entitled Japanese
Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925-1975, Johnson
distinguished two basic components of the industrial policy in Japan,
corresponding to micro and macro aspects of the economy; the first - industrial
rationalisation policy, and the second
-
industrial structure policy. ‘Industrial rationalisation means:
(1) the rationalisation of enterprises, that is, the adoption of new techniques
of production, investment in new equipment and facilities, quality control,
cost reduction, adoption of new management techniques, and the perfection of
managerial control; (2) the rationalisation of the environment of enterprises,
including land and water transportation and industrial location; (3) the
rationalisation of whole industries, meaning the creation of a framework for
all enterprises in an industry in which each can compete fairly or in which
they can cooperate in a cartel-like arrangement of mutual assistance; and (4)
the rationalisation of the industrial structure itself in order to meet
international competitive standards’.[32]
Industrial structure policy ‘concerns the proportions of agriculture, mining,
manufacturing, and services in the nations total production; and within
manufacturing it concerns the percentages of light and heavy and of
labour-intensive and knowledge-intensive industries. The application of the
policy comes in the governments attempts to change these proportions in ways it
deems advantageous to the nation. [...] The heart of the policy is the
selection of the strategic industries to be developed or converted to other
lines of work’[33].
Kagami underlines that throughout the period of Japans rapid growth there were
many IP definitions, which appeared in the scholarly literature, ranging from
all MITI[34]
activities, via most policies intervening into the national industry, to
selective actions within certain industries[35].
He focuses his IP analysis on market limitations as the main reason to
implement industrial policies, and following Goto and Idre he divides them
into: traditional and recently added market failures, and market imperfections.
He pays
Andrzej Bolesta
special
attention to the economy of scale concept (internal and external) and to
Marshallian externalities and start-up costs. The “internal” economies of scale
concern the decreasing cost of production per unit with the increasing volume
of production and with the accumulated knowledge of workers (so-called dynamic
economies of scale). ‘The “external” economies of scale mean that the average
production cost in related industries declines in proportion to a production
expansion in the main industry’[36],
for example, in the case of “network effects” or “Marshallian externalities”,
when improvements in the main industry trigger improvements in related
industries thanks to knowledge dissemination. Kim in his analysis of Korea
considers industrial policy to be ‘all government policy measures that are
aimed at promoting the development of [national] industry’[37].
However, he distinguishes between those industrial promotional measures, which
exert an economy-wide impact and those - industry-specific.
The general
approach to industrialisation in developmental states is concerned, firstly,
with import substitution industrialisation (ISI) and then, with
export-orientated industrialisation (EOI). This industrialisation starts with
import-substitution industrialisation, where a state gradually replaces
imported goods with domestically manufactured products. According to Haggard,
‘ISI may occur “naturally” as the result of balance-of-payments problems,
supply interruptions associated with wars or growth of the domestic market. ISI
is advanced, however, by policies to manage balance-of- payments crises,
particularly trade and exchange controls, and by explicit industrial policies
designed to raise the rate of return to manufacturing’[38].
Haggard distinguishes three phases of ISI. ‘In the first stage, the state
earnings come from primary-product exports and the foreign borrowing finance
the imports of selected producer goods. These imports provide the foundation
for local manufacturing’[39].
In its second stage, the dependency on raw material and food exports as well as
on foreign borrowing is maintained, ‘since investment in new industrial
capacity increases the demand for imported capital and intermediate goods’[40].
The third phase is characterised by the supplementing of import substitution
with the expansion of manufactured exports. Thus, ISI gradually moves towards
export-oriented industrialisation or EOI. The EOI would create a structural
relation of a developmental state with the world economy[41],
in which the world economy would become the market for the national production,
The East
Asian industrial policy: a critical analysis of the developmental state
excessive to
the domestic consumption capacities. Another important DS policy aspect
concerns industrial upgrading, i.e. a gradual and continuous change of the
assortment of industrial production towards higher sophistication and
technological advancement. According to Bernard and Ravenhill industrial
upgrading was the key issue for East Asian developmental states[42].
The initial
phase of industrialisation ‘has come about as a process of learning rather than
of generation of inventions and innovations’[43],
as the late developers were in the position to “borrow” existing technologies[44].
Therefore, the industrial targeting would need to be primarily focused on those
industries, who would contribute to the broad strategy of the overall catching
up, rather than single out exclusively sectors associated with advanced
technologies. These industries would usually possess the potential of their
products becoming widely desirable on the international market.
In practice,
preferential treatment of what would be adequately technologically- advanced
production became an important feature of the East Asian industrial policy and
indigenous innovation has been a vital element of the East Asian developmental
model. Adequate levels of innovation would be achieved via investment in
R&D and/or import of technologies. The quality of R&D could be achieved
through the attraction of foreign specialists and experts, as well as foreign
technologies, in the short term, whereas long-term effects would be achieved
via the creation of a local intellectual base composed of scientists and
engineers. This would necessitate a constant nurturing of human capital
formation via the expansion of the training base/facilities.
Although
Japan is considered to belong to the “late developers” group, hence the initial
process of innovation would suggest an importation and duplication of
technologies, Japans rather early developmental start in the late developers
group, as well as a general lack of a generic Asian policy of major FDI
attraction, suggest that throughout the high growth period Japan, to some
important extent, relied on its own R&D. Indeed, already at the beginning
of the twentieth century, Japans expansion in cotton textile production was
attributed to the utilisation of new technologies and adequate managerial
coordination based on indigenous experiences and patterns. Mass and Miyajima point to the establishment of
experimental industrial laboratories aimed initially at developing new
technologies in the textile industries, as far as dyeing of material is
concerned, as an example of R&D orientation[45].
This policy, as well as the earlier efforts of the Meiji s administration
focused on the development of educational base resulted in a very high position
of Japan in ranking of the Human Capital Index even among developed nations.
The subsequent “targeting” of industries for development took into
consideration the advantages of becoming innovative; hence offering
technologically more advanced products. This is not to say that Japan refrained
itself from importing necessary technologies. On the contrary, the American
companies were especially targeted for the transfer of technology. Initially,
‘Japan imported [...] technology for its basic and high-growth industries, and
imported the greater proportion of this technology from the United States’[46].
The government was in charge of technology transfers and no technology would
enter the country without MITIs approval. Based on Foreign Capital and Foreign
Exchange Control Law, ‘the Japanese government allocated its scarce foreign
currency selectively to those firms capable of adapting and improving import
technology, in order to encourage the importation of advanced technology and to
promote a domestic technology base[47].
Subsequently, ‘technological development was supported by direct and indirect
production and R&D subsidies, the encouragement of multifirm research
consortia, the discouragement of foreign direct investment in sectors in which
it was technologically feasible for Japan to enter’[48].
The proof of a strong R&D base was delivered during the early 1970 s when
Japan commenced reorganisation of its industrial sector towards future
promising branches such as computer industry and electronics. As a result, by
late 1970 s, Japan became the world leader in semiconductor technology,
following the MITIs vision of “technology-based nation”.
Korea found
itself in favourable conditions as far as the process of learning and
innovating is concerned. In the early twentieth century, the state was seen by
its coloniser - Japan as an important supply base for further Japanese
expansion in Asia, hence the development of the country was viewed by the
Japanese as crucial. This is why Korea’s rapid and extensive industrialisation
commenced under the Japanese rule. The first Korean companies[49]
derived their innovation from imitating the Japanese firms and from heavily
relying on transfer of technology from Japan. During the high growth period of
the 1960 s and 1970 s, Korea continued to rely on foreign technologies for its
industries, partly benefiting from the US overall assistance. Nevertheless, in
the early 1980 s the government commenced the reorganisation of development
trajectory into knowledge- and information-intensive industries, in which local
R&D would play a crucial role. By Cho et al
this period is called “creative knowledge intensive era”[50].
The alleged initial low position in rankings on the Human Capital Index
resulted in Korea’s government paying more attention to the education of
scientists and engineers. Chun points out that science-profiled high schools
were for that reason supervised by the Ministry of Commerce, Industry and
Energy and not by the Ministry of Education[51].
As early as in the 1960 s, the government established the Korea Institute of
Science and Technology responsible for developing industrial technology and the
Korea Development Institute for conducting research on development policy.
Foreign specialists were continuously attracted via income and
career-development incentives. Korea became a good example of effective human
capital accumulation.
Certain
industrial sectors were deliberately targeted by the state for development, due
to their real or potential value for the national economy. During the high
growth period, Japanese governments targeting encompassed various sectors. In
the early days, the priority was given to production of coal, iron and steel,
as a part of the “priority production programme”. It should be seen as the
continuation of the pre-war heavy industry development focused then on the
military equipment, which would accompany the expansion of textile production
from the late nineteenth century. Later, the focus also included electric power
building and shipbuilding, as well as petrochemicals to produce synthetic fibre
and chemical fertiliser, among others. According to Cumings, this assortment of
targeting represented the second phase of Japans industrialisation, which
commenced in the 1930 s and was completed by the mid-1960s[52].
The late 1940s efforts were mainly focused on reconstruction of pre-war
industrial sectors, whereas the theme of the 1950 s industrialisation became
the industrial catching-up. A similar recovery after the Korean war determined
the initial targeting policies of the South Korean government, which included
cement and glass as well as refined oil products. Nevertheless, attention was
directed shortly afterwards towards light industry.
In the 1960
s, the Japanese government continued promoting heavy as well as chemical
industries (HCI). Heavy industry remained strategic at least until 1970.[53]
However, more focus was directed towards machinery and automobile
industry. Although the Korean government also started paying more attention to
heavy and chemical industries, as a potential export orientated production,
nevertheless, the production was dominated by the light industry, including
textiles.
In the 1970 s
the Japanese targeting focused on machine productions and electronic
industries, including computer industry. Undoubtedly, it was partly caused by
the 1973 oil shock, as a result of which a number of energy-intensive
industries such as aluminium, chemicals, and steel, found themselves in
decline. Despite that, in 1973 Park Chung Hee announced its strategy of
heavy-chemical industrialisation in Korea[54].
HCI became a priority sector. As much as in Japan during the 1950 s, the
production of iron, steel, petrochemicals and non-ferrous metals became
strategically important. The government also promoted the construction of
shipyards.
From the late
1970 s, high-tech products became the main target for the Japanese governments
preferential treatment and the governmental support for R&D increased. In
the late 1970 s the Koreans accelerated the development of heavy and chemical
industries, with the emphasis on industrial machinery, steel and electric
equipment, whereas in the 1980 s, similar to Japan, redirected its attention to
knowledge- and information-intensive industries. The change from labour
intensive to knowledge intensive industries in both cases was also dictated by
the rapidly increasing cost of labour. Needless to say, the targeting of
industries was consequently reflected in the assortments of export goods.
All the East
Asian fast developers prove that export was an important drive behind the fast
socio-economic development. The trade policy would involve the establishment of
barriers for import and incentives for export. The import substitution
industrialisation (ISI) would include import barriers. Export orientated
industrialisation (EOI) would involve export promotion. In Japan, the strategy
was already present in the years 1914-1938, when the state became a world
leading textile exporter. The cartelisation process was accompanied by
increased import tariffs and anti-dumping laws. After world war two, Japan
followed a similar path. Up until 1975 it was domestic consumption, and thus
ISI, which drove its economic growth. All international trade was under governments
direct control (until the early 1950 s). Later, two factors caused the steady
climb of average trade tariffs rate, namely; gradual reduction of tariff
exemption for machinery and the increase in tariffs on food imports. For
example, sugar customs duties hiked from 15% in 1951 to 100% in 1959[55].
Import substitution production was additionally enhanced via the exercising of
strict control over import, mostly via quota systems, where in the 1960 s
almost 500 types of goods were under the import quota system, including steel
products (as early as in 1950). Economic liberalisation moved Japan closer to
an EOI pattern. However, this liberalisation focused on eliminating quota-style
quantitative restrictions, whereas tariffs continued to be important tools in
restraining imports. The agreements brokered during the GATT’s Kennedy Round
(1964-1967) effected a gradual decrease in Japanese tariffs from the late 1960
s. In the early 1970 s, the government implemented a number of effective tariff
reductions on mining and manufacturing products, as well as on agricultural
goods. In the late 1970 s, the measures to prevent import and promote export
were gradually eliminated, whereas in the early 1980 s the policy of import
promotion took place, in order to balance the Japanese trade surplus.
‘Until the
late 1950s, Korea was a typical inward-orientated economy[56].
Soon after the Park Chung Hee took over power, the EOI became the dominant
focus. The government introduced various export incentives. Nevertheless,
export, was closely monitored, to the extent that the decisions on the product
type, the exporter and the targeted market were greatly influenced by the state
administration. Moreover, the ‘Ministry of Commerce and Industry set annual
export targets for officials connected with export administration[57].
At the same time, protection of the domestic market played an important role.
The government tightened import control, while the general import tariffs rose
to 40%. The tariffs diversification and tariffs exemptions allowed the
government to steer the inflow of goods and capital. For example, intermediate
goods for export production and some capital goods for special uses or specific
industries were imported duty free. Imposed import quotas were awarded to
companies proportionally, according to their export volume (the export-import
link). Although the first attempts at import liberalisation took place already
in the late 1960 s, the effective policy took shape in the 1980 s.
To nurture
the development of certain industries, as well as to boost export, the state
policy would involve the direct and indirect channelling of financial
assistance via banks or state institutions in the form of credit subsidies and
other subsidies, regulatory actions such as domestic tax policies and price
control mechanisms, as well as monetary policies such as the manipulation of
interest rates and exchange rates. All those policies are sometimes classified
as subsidies related.
Banks have
realised a policy of indirect subsidies offering preferential rate loans for
designated sectors and designated enterprises. These were usually described as
policy loans or subsidised general loans. The mechanism was based on subsidised
interest rates, and the market distortion in Korea became so significant that
export loans had negative real interest rates. Woo distinguished three ways of
generating policy loans in Korea - from the banking system, the fiscal-type
taken out of the state budget, and from the National Investment Fund (since
1973)[58].
In the 1970 s policy loans accounted for over 40% of domestic credit.
Preferential loans were initially granted for the textile industries and later
- for export and all the HCI sectors, including transport infrastructure,
energy and defence. In Japan, capital channelling to preferred sectors was
implemented through direct subsidies, indirect subsidies through state-owned or
dominated banks, and preferential tax breaks such as accelerated depreciation
on investment’[59].
Policy loans mostly benefited the targeted industries - iron and steel
production, electric power and shipbuilding. A direct credit allocation to
selected industries on concessional terms was supplemented by governmental
direct subsidies.
Direct
subsidies featured already in Japan for the designated textile production
industry. The Japanese government used the Fiscal Investment and Loan Programme
in the endeavour of selective investment in targeted sectors and enterprises,
whereas in Korea this role was fulfilled by the National Investment Fund. In
Japan, the initial purpose of the direct allocation of foreign reserves was to
purchase foreign technologies. It is important to emphasise that the
preferential policy of direct and indirect subsidies was not only directed at
targeted industries, but also - at particular enterprises. In Korea, especially
during the HCI targeting, the subsidies were given to certain enterprises, who
managed to gain favour from Park Chung Hee.
These
subsidies also took the form of various tax subsidies. In general, tax
policies, meaning favourable treatment for certain activities, i.e. lower
taxes, tax deductions, tax exemptions and special depreciation for tax
purposes, were all used towards targeted sectors and enterprises in the case of
Japan and Korea. In the 1950 s the Japanese government introduced various tax
incentive policies for industrial development, as well as export development,
namely, special depreciation (1951), import tax exemption for import of
machinery (1952), export-import link tax reduction (1953). The fiscal policies
served to attract modern technology. “Inclined taxation system” provided
generous corporate tax exemption arrangements in purchasing specific types of
machinery and equipment, and accelerated the introduction of foreign
technologies[60].
In Korea, ‘the 1961 Tax Exemption and Reduction Control Law began to provide
export firms with tax deduction measures’[61].
The subsequent policies focused on tax exemptions and tax deductions, as well
as accelerated tax depreciation on profits from export activities, in targeted
HCI such as steel, chemical, shipbuilding and machinery, and eventually in 1982
- on R&D related activities[62].
* * *
The
contemporary applicability?
The above
analysis leads us to the question of possible scenarios as far as the
contemporary applicability of the concept of the developmental state is
concerned. Is there space for it to be applied in the times of globalisation?
Can any state benefit from it? How far can state intervention go? The concept
is often seen as merely a historical phenomenon, which brought extensive
developmental achievements in very specific exogenic and endogenic conditions.
It would thus be naive to believe that all its provisions can be transplanted
into systemic arrangements of underdeveloped countries contemporarily. However,
there are undoubtedly some lessons to be learned.
The question
of DS contemporary applicability is inevitably connected with the discussion on
the positioning of the state and state interventionism in the times of
globalisation. The gradual disappearance of regulatory barriers in economic
interactions between the states, the regions and the economic sectors seems to
be advancing. However, some barriers disappear, but in their place new
mechanisms of protection are created. It is a popular opinion that the new
rules favour strong entities within the global economy and marginalise the weak
ones, including developing countries. Consequently, the dismissal of a scenario
in which the role of the state will still be crucial, upon the conviction that
a one borderless global economy is rapidly emerging, seems premature. On the
contrary, the role of the state will most likely remain extremely important to
fend the national interests, as the 2008/2009 financial crisis clearly
illustrates, allowing space for the possible utilisation of the provisions of
the DS model.
The actual
process of globalisation has left many nations and a plethora of social groups
dissatisfied. The development-related disparities are increasing. Although some
manage to accumulate significant wealth, the majority remains only marginally
better off. Again, this is because a more aggressively enforced
internationalisation of the global economy, [has been] built around rules that
work primarily to the benefit of current holders of financial capital’[63].
In this situation, only states are believed to offer adequate political
resources to avert and redirect the process to make it more socially equitable,
and the nations seem prone to turn towards interventionist practices to achieve
better developmental dynamics.
Naturally,
globalisation, understood as a multilevel integration of national and regional
economies and as a growth of interdependence of various socio-economic
processes worldwide, will most likely continue in one form or another and the
pressure of the external economic environment to influence the processes
internally, will continue to take place. This is what constitutes the
predicament of “late-late” development, as described by Beeson[64].
Therefore, state needs to play an important role in poor countries, who require
better developmental dynamics, by attempting to benefit from international
conditionality (e.g. from trade liberalisation, from easier technology
diffusion) and by resisting external threats (such as attempts by foreign
economic agents/actors to overtake certain domestic industrial sectors in order
to eliminate possible competition).
Moreover, in
view of relatively recent East Asian economic achievements and the lack thereof
in other regions, the necessity for creating developmental states cannot be
easily dismissed. In reality, we are clearly observing DS features being more
prominent in contemporary policy making. The governments are becoming less shy
to speak about interventionism and regulation to nurture development. Even
places considered to be the bastions of the neo-liberalism thought
implementation seem to be giving in. International organisations such as the
OECD have begun admitting the successes of the developmental state model.
Institutional
arrangements enabling state-guided development, policy solutions focusing on
industrial development and a selective engagement with the global economy and
state ideology defending national economic interests can all, in one way or
another, be considered for a broader audience. The process of rejection of
neo-liberalism is accompanied by an increase in the interest in a variation of
the DS arrangements in other continents than Asia. It is interesting to see how
the DS model becomes more prominent in Africa. The continent is seen as the new
high growth region, with challenges similar to those faced earlier by East
Asian economies, mostly related to a large incidence of poverty. It is then by
all means natural that the discussion on adequate development models therein
also includes that which brought the biggest successes in the second half of
the twentieth century. The idea of constructing an African developmental state
has floated around at least since the 1990 s[65]
and is indeed believed to have peaked in the twenty first century. Due to its
authoritarian political arrangements and high growth, Ethiopia is often
mentioned as a possible example[66].
However, as many countries on the continent have been undergoing
democratisation processes, the African developmental state has been connected
with the constructing of a democratic developmental state[67].
References
Akamatsu K., A Historical Pattern of Economic Growth in Developing Countries, “Journal of Developing Economies” 1962, no. 1(1).
American Industry in International Competition: Government
Policies and Corporate Strategies, eds. J. Zysman, L. Tyson, Cornell University Press, Ithaca-London 1983.
Amsden A.H., Asias Next
Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialisation, Oxford University Press, Oxford 1989.
Beeson M., The Rise and Fall (?) of the
Developmental State: The Vicissitudes and Implications of East Asian
Interventionism, in: Developmental
States: Relevancy Redundancy or Reconfiguration?, ed. L. Low, Nova Science Publishers, New York 2004.
Bernard M., Ravenhill J., Beyond
Product Cycles and Flying Geese: Regionalization, Hierarchy, and the Industrialization
of East Asia, “World Politics” 1995, no. 47(2).
Chacko G., Evans C.L., Gunawan H., Sjoman A., The Global
Economic System: How Liquidity Shocks Affect Financial Institutions and Lead to
Economic Crises, FT Press, New
Jersey 2011.
Chang H.-J., 23 Things They Don't Tell You About Capitalism, Penguin Books, London 2010.
Chang H.-J., Industrial Policy: Can We Go Beyond an Unproductive
Confrontation?, A Plenary Paper for ABCDE - Annual World Bank
Conference on Development Economics, 22-24 June 2009, Seoul, South Korea.
Chang H.-J., Kicking Away
the Ladder. Development Strategy in Historical Perspective, Anthem Press, London 2002.
Chang H.-J., The Economic Theory of the Developmental State, in: The
Developmental State, ed. M. Woo-Cumings, Cornell University
Press, Ithaca 1999.
Cho D.-S., Lee D.-H., Ryu S.-J., Cho D.-W, Kim D.-J., Comparative
Study of Korean and Japanese Industrial Policies Though Content Analysis of
Official Documents, “Hitotsubashi Journal of Commerce and
Management” 1996, no. 31(1).
Chun S.-H., Economic Development, and Tax Policy and Tax System in Korea,
“Research Paper”, Korea Institute of Public Finance, Seoul 2002.
Cimoli M., Dosi G., Stiglitz J.E., The Political Economy of
Capabilities Accumulation: The Past and Future of Policies for Industrial
Development, in: Industrial
Policy and Development: The Political Economy of Capabilities Accumulation, ed. M. Cimoli et al, Oxford University Press, Oxford 2009.
Cooper G., The Origin of Financial Crises:
Central Banks, Credit Bubbles and the Efficient Market Fallacy, Harriman House Ltd., Petersfield 2008.
Cumings B., The Origins and Development of the
Northeast Asian Political Economy. Industrial Sectors, Product Cycles and
Political Consequences, “International Organization” 1984, no. 38(1).
Desta A., Emerging Challenges in Democratic Developmental State: The Case of
Ethiopian Growth and Transformation, http://aigaforum.com/articles/democratic_developmental_state.pdf
Doner R.F., Ritchie B.K., Slater D., Systemic
Vulnerability and the Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast
Asia in Comparative Perspective, “International 327 Organization” 2005, no. 59.
Edigheji O., A Democratic Developmental State in Africa?, “A
Concept Paper, Research Report”, Centre for Policy Studies 2005, no. 105.
Enlarging
Europe: The Industrial Foundations of a New Political Reality, eds. J. Zysman, A. Schwartz, University of California,
Berkeley 1998.
Evans R, Transferable Lessons? Re-Examining
the Institutional Prerequisites of East Asian Economic Policies, “Journal of Development Studies” 1998, no. 34(6).
Financial
Institutions and Markets: The Financial Crisis - An Early Retrospective, eds. R.R. Bliss, G.G. Kaufman, Palgrave MacMillan, New York
2010.
Foster J.B., McChesney R.W., The Endless
Crisis: How Monopoly-Finance Capital Produces Stagnation and Upheaval from the
USA to China, “Monthly Review Press”, New York 2012.
Gerschenkron A., Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, The
Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge 1962.
Giddens A., The
Politics of Climate Change, Polity Press, Cambridge 2009.
Goldstein M., The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic
Implications, “Policy Analyses in International Economics” 1998,
Institute for International Economics.
Graham O.L., Losing
Time: The Industrial Policy Debate, Harvard University Press,
Harvard 1992.
Haggard S., Institutions
and Growth in East Asia, “Studies in Comparative International
Development” 2004, no. 38 (4).
Haggard S., Pathways
from the Periphery, Cornell University Press, Ithaca 1990.
Haggard S., The
Political Economy of the Asian Financial Crisis, Institute for
International Economics, Washington DC 2000.
Haggard S., Cooper R.N., Collins S., Kim Ch., Ro S.-T., Macroeconomic
Policy and Adjustment in Korea, 1970-1990, “Harvard Studies in
International Development”, Harvard Institute for International Development,
Harvard University Press, Cambridge 1994.
Hamilton A., The Revolutionary Writings of Alexander Hamilton, Liberty Fund, Indianapolis 2008.
Jeon J.-G., Exploring the Three Varieties of
East Asia's State-Guided Development Model: Korea, Signapore, and Taiwan, “Studies in Comparative International Development” 1995,
no. 30 (3).
nr 2(2)2014
Johnson Ch., MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy;
1925-1975, Stanford University Press, Stanford 1982.
Joyce J.P., The
IMF and Global Financial Crises: Phoenix Rising?, Cambridge
University Press, New York 2013.
Kagami M., The
Role of Industrial Policy: Japans Experience, aRevista
de Economia Politica” 1995, no. 15(1).
Kefale A., Narratives of Developmentalism and Development in Ethiopia: Some
Preliminary Explorations, Paper submitted for the 4th European
Conference on African Studies, Uppsala 15-18 June 2011.
Kim K.S., Industrial Policy and Industrialization
in South Korea: 1961-1982 - Lessons on Industrial Policies for Other Developing
Countries, “Kellogg Institute Working Paper” 1985, no. 39.
Kimura E, Japans Model of Economic
Development: Relevant and Nonrelevant Elements for Developing Economies, “WIDER Working Paper” 2009, no. 22.
Kobayashi Y., The Role and
Significance of Japanese Industrial Policy: Its Estimation and Recent Issue, “Economic Journal of Hokkaido University” 1993, no. 22.
Kohli A., Where Do High Growth Political
Economies Come From? The Japanese Lineage of Korea's, Developmental State, “World Development” 1994, no. 22(9).
Kolb R. W, The
Financial Crisis of Our Time, Oxford University Press, New York
2011.
Krugman R, Targeted Industrial Policy: Theory and Evidence,
“Industrial Change and Public Policy” 1983, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, Kansas City.
Levin C., Coburn T., Wall Street and the Financial
Crisis: The Anatomy of a Financial Collapse, Majority and
Minority Staff Report, Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, United States
Senate, 13th April 2011.
Lindbeck A., Industrial
Policy as an Issue in the Economic Environment, “World Economy” 1981, no. 4.
Mah J.S., Export Promotion Policies, Export Composition and Economic
Development of Korea, Paper prepared for the Law and Development
Institute Inaugural Conference, Sydney 2010.
Mass W, Miyajima H., The Organization of the Developmental State: Fostering Private
Capabilities and the Roots of the Japanese “Miracle”, “Business and Economic History” 1993, no. 22(1).
Mkandawire T., Thinking about Developmental States in Africa,
“Cambridge Journal of Economics” 2001, no. 25(3).
Morek R., Nakamura
M., The
History of Corporate Ownership in Japan, “ECGI Working Paper
Series in Finance” 2003, no. 20.
Nam Ch.-H., The Role of Trade and Exchange
Rate Policy in Korea's Growth, in: Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience, eds. T. Ito, A. Krueger, University of Chicago Press,
Chicago 1995.
Noland M., From Industrial Policy to
Innovation Policy: Japans Pursuit of Competitive Advantage, “Asian Economic Policy Review” 2007, no. 2.
Olayode K., Reinventing the African State:
Issues and Challenges for Building a Developmental State, “African Journal of International Affairs” 2005, no.
8(1-2).
Pack H., Saggi K., The Case for Industrial Policy: A Critical Survey,
“World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series” 2006, no. 3839.
Page J., The East Asian Miracle: Four Lessons for Development Policy,
“NBER Macroeconomics Annual” 1994, vol. 9, eds. S. Fischer, J.J. Rotemberg, MIT
Press.
Quinn D.P., Jacobson R., Industrial
Policy through the Restriction of Capital Flows: A Test of Several Claims Made
about Industrial Policy, “American Journal of Political Science” 1989, no. 33(3).
Recent
Financial Crises: Analyses, Challenges and Implications, eds. L.R.
Klein, T. Shabbir, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham 2006.
Rodrik D., Industrial Policy: Dont Ask Why, Ask How, “Middle
East Development Journal” 2008, no. 1(1).
Rodrik D., Normalizing
Industrial Policy, “The World Bank Working Paper” 2008, vol. 1.
Sakakibara M., Cho D.-S., Cooperative
R&D in Japan and Korea: A Comparison of Industrial Policy, “Research Policy” 2002, no. 31(5).
Scott B.R., Capitalism: Its Origins and Evolution as a System of Governance, Springer, New York 2011.
Shapiro H., Industrial
Policy and Growth, “DESA Working Paper” 2007, no. 53.
Stiglitz J.E., The Stiglitz
Report: Reforming the International Monetary and Financial Systems in the Wake
of the Global Crisis, The New Press,
New York-London 2010.
Time
for A Visible Hand: Lessons from the 2008 World Financial Crisis, eds. S.
Griffith-Jones, J.A. Ocampo, J.E. Stiglitz, Oxford University Press, New York
2010.
ul Haque I., Rethinking Industrial Policy, “Discussion Papers
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development” 2007, no. 183.
Wade R., Governing the Market: Economic
Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton University Press, Princeton New Jersey 1990.
Woo J.-E., Race to the Swift: The Role of
Finance in Korean Industrialization, Columbia University Press, New York 1991.
Woo W.T., The Changing Ingredients in Industrial Policy for Economic Growth,
Paper presented at the Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network (ARTNeT)
Symposium Towards a Return of Industrial Policy?, 25-26 July
2011, ESCAP, Bangkok.
World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic
Growth and Public Policy, World Bank, Washington DC 1993.
Yamazawa I., Trade Policy and Changes in Japans Trade Structure - With Special
Reference to Labour-Intensive Manufactures, “The Developing Economies” 1975.
nr 2(2)2014
[1] See, for example, Financial
Institutions and Markets: The Financial Crisis - An Early Retrospective, eds. R.R. Bliss, G.G. Kaufman, Palgrave MacMillan, New
York 2010; G. Cooper, The Origin of Financial Crises: Central Banks, Credit Bubbles and
the Efficient Market Fallacy, Harriman House Ltd., Petersfield 2008; J.B. Foster, R.W. McChesney, The Endless
Crisis: How Monopoly-Finance Capital Produces Stagnation and Upheaval from the
USA to China, “Monthly Review Press”, New York 2012.
[2] See, for example, M. Goldstein, The
Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic Implications,
“Policy Analyses in International Economics” 1998, Institute for International
Economics, p. 55; S. Haggard, The Political Economy of the Asian Financial Crisis,
eds. L.R. Klein, T. Shabbir, Institute for International Economics, Washington
DC 2000; Recent Financial Crises: Analyses, Challenges and Implications,
Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham 2006.
[3] J.E. Stiglitz, The Stiglitz
Report: Reforming the International Monetary and Financial Systems in the Wake
of the Global Crisis, The New Press,
New York-London 2010.
[4] R. W. Kolb, The Financial
Crisis of Our Time, Oxford
University Press, New York 2011; G. Chacko, C.L. Evans, H. Gunawan, A. Sjoman, The Global
Economic System: How Liquidity Shocks Affect Financial Institutions and Lead to
Economic Crises, FT Press, New Jersey 2011.
[5] C. Levin, T. Coburn, Wall Street
and the Financial Crisis: The Anatomy of a Financial Collapse,
Majority and Minority Staff Report, Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations,
United States Senate, 13 th April 2011.
[6] J.E. Stiglitz, op.cit., p. 1. See also: J.P.
Joyce, The
IMF and Global Financial Crises: Phoenix Rising?, Cambridge
University Press, New York 2013.
[7] B.R.
Scott, Capitalism: Its Origins and Evolution as a System of Governance, Springer, New York
2011, p. 611.
[8] Time
for A Visible Hand: Lessons from the 2008
World Financial Crisis, eds. S.
Griffith-Jones, J.A. Ocampo, J.E. Stiglitz, Oxford University Press, New York
2010.
[9] A. Giddens, The Politics
of Climate Change, Polity Press, Cambridge 2009.
[10] H.-J. Chang, 23 Things
They Don t Tell You About Capitalism, Penguin Books, London 2010,
p. 337.
nr 2(2)2014
[11] In the case of Japan, the high growth
period is believed to have taken place from the 1950 s, until early 1980 s. In
the case of Korea, this is counted roughly from the mid-1960s until early 1990
s.
[12] A. Hamilton, The
Revolutionary Writings of Alexander Hamilton, Liberty Fund,
Indianapolis 2008.
[13] The Meiji restoration (1868-1912) was
the process of significant changes in Japans political, social and economic
structures, which accelerated the country’s industrialisation.
nr 2(2)2014
[14] H.-J. Chang, The Economic
Theory of the Developmental State, in: The
Developmental State, ed. M. Woo-Cumings, Cornell University
Press, Ithaca 1999, p. 182-199.
[15] M. Cimoli,
G. Dosi,
J.E. Stiglitz, The Political
Economy of Capabilities Accumulation: The Past and Future of Policies for
Industrial Development, in: Industrial
Policy and Development: The Political Economy of Capabilities Accumulation, eds. M. Cimoli et al., Oxford University Press, Oxford
2009, p. 1-2.
[16] D. Rodrik, Normalizing
Industrial Policy, Paper prepared for the Commission on Growth
and Development, 2007, p. 3.
[17] A. Lindbeck,
Industrial Policy as an Issue in the Economic Environment, “World Economy” 1981, no. 4, p. 391-405.
[18] S. Haggard, Institutions
and Growth in East Asia, “Studies in Comparative International
Development” 2004, no. 38 (4), p. 64.
[19] H.-J. Chang, Industrial
Policy: Can We Go Beyond an Unproductive Confrontation?, A
Plenary Paper for ABCDE Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics
2009,22-24 June 2009, p. 2.
[20] I. ul Haque, Rethinking
Industrial Policy, “UNCTAD Discussion Papers” 2007, no. 183, p.
3.
Studia z Polityki Publicznej
[21] See: P. Krugman, Targeted
Industrial Policy: Theory and Evidence, “Industrial Change and
Public Policy” 1983, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas City; H. Pack,
K. Saggi, The Case for Industrial Policy: A Critical Survey,
“World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series” 2006, no. 3839; J. Page, The
East Asian Miracle: Four Lessons for Development Policy, “NBER
Macroeconomics Annual” 1994, vol. 9, eds. S. Fischer, J.J. Rotemberg, MIT
Press, p. 219-282; D.P. Quinn, R. Jacobson, Industrial
Policy through the Restriction of Capital Flows: A Test of Several Claims Made
about Industrial Policy, “American Journal of Political Science”
1989, no. 33 (3), p. 700-736; W.T. Woo, The Changing Ingredients in
Industrial Policy for Economic Growth, Paper presented at the
Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network (ARTNeT) Symposium Towards a
Return of Industrial Policy? 2011,25-26 July, ESCAP, Bangkok;
World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy,
World Bank, Washington DC 1993.
[22] D. Rodrik, op.cit.
[23] M. Cimoli,
G. Dosi,
J.E. Stiglitz, op.cit. See also: A.H. Amsden, Asias Next
Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialisation, Oxford University Press, Oxford 1989; H.-J. Chang, Kicking Away
the Ladder. Development Strategy in Historical Perspective, Anthem Press, London 2002; D. Rodrik, Industrial
Policy: Don't Ask Why, Ask How, “Middle East Development Journal” 2008, no. 1(1), p. 1-29; R. Wade, Governing the
Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian
Industrialisation, Princeton
University Press, Princeton 1990; Enlarging
Europe: The Industrial Foundations of a New Political Reality, eds. J. Zysman, A. Schwartz, University of California,
Berkeley 1998; American Industry in International Competition: Government
Policies and Corporate Strategies, eds. J. Zysman, L. Tyson, Cornell University Press, Ithaca-London
1983.
[24] O.L. Graham, Losing Time:
The Industrial Policy Debate, Harvard University Press, Harvard
1992.
[25] D. Rodrik, Normalizing...,
op.cit., p. 6-7.
[26] H. Shapiro, Industrial
Policy and Growth, “DESA Working Paper” 2007, no. 53, p. 2.
[27] H.-J. Chang, Industrial
Policy: Can We Go..., op.cit.
nr 2(2)2014
[28] I. ul Haque, Rethinking
Industrial Policy, “Discussion Papers United Nations Conference
on Trade and Development” 2007, no. 183, p. 1.
[29] K. Akamatsu, A Historical
Pattern of Economic Growth in Developing Countries, “Journal of
Developing Economies” 1962, no. 1 (1), p. 3-25.
[30] B. Cumings, The Origins
and Development of the Northeast Asian Political Economy. Industrial Sectors,
Product Cycles and Political Consequences, “International Organization” 1984, no. 38 (1), p. 1-40; R.F. Doner,
B.K. Ritchie, D. Slater, Systemic Vulnerability and the
Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast Asia in Comparative
Perspective, “International 327 Organization” 2005, no. 59,
p. 361; A. Kohli, Where Do High Growth Political Economies Come From? The Japanese
Lineage of Korea's, Developmental State, “World Development” 1994, no. 22 (9), p. 1269-1293; R. Wade, op.cit.
[31] H.-J. Chang, Industrial
Policy: Can We Go..., op.cit, p. 3.
[32] Ch. Johnson,
MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy,
1925-1975, Stanford University Press, Stanford 1982, p.
27.
[33] Ibidem, p. 28.
[34] The Ministry of International Trade
and Industry of Japan (1949-2001) is considered to have been one of the most
influential and powerful governmental agencies in the Japanese government
structure.
[35] M. Kagami, The Role of
Industrial Policy: Japans Experience, “Revista de Economia
Politica” 1995, no. 15 (1), p. 119-133.
nr 2(2)2014
[36] Ibidem, p. 121.
[37] K.S. Kim, Industrial
Policy and Industrialization in South Korea: 1961-1982 - Lessons on Industrial
Policies for Other Developing Countries, “Kellogg Institute Working Paper” 1985, no. 39, p. 16.
[38] S. Haggard, Pathways from
the Periphery, Cornell University Press, Ithaca 1990, p. 26.
[39] Ibidem, p. 25-26.
[40] Ibidem, p. 26.
[41] Ibidem.
[42] M. Bernard,
J. Ravenhill, Beyond Product Cycles and Flying Geese: Regionalization, Hierarchy,
and the Industrialization of East Asia, “World Politics” 1995, no. 47 (2), p. 171-209.
[43] A.H. Amsden, op.cit, p. 4.
[44] A. Gerschenkron, Economic
Backwardness in Historical Perspective, The Belknap Press of
Harvard University Press, Cambridge 1962.
nr 2(2)2014
[45] W. Mass, H.
Miyajima, The Organization of the Developmental State: Fostering Private
Capabilities and the Roots of the Japanese “Miracle”, "Business and Economic History” 1993, no. 22 (1), p. 151-168.
[46] Ch. Johnson, op.cit., p. 16.
[47] M. Sakakibara, D.-S. Cho, Cooperative
R&D in Japan and Korea: A Comparison of Industrial Policy, “Research
Policy” 2002, no. 31 (5), p. 678.
[48] M. Noland, From
Industrial Policy to Innovation Policy: Japans Pursuit of Competitive
Advantage, “Asian Economic Policy Review” 2007, no. 2, p.
255.
[49] The companies set up in Korea were initially
the Japanese zaibatsu such as Mitsui and Mitsubishi. Both
companies became keiretsu after world war two. See: R. Morek, M. Nakamura, The History
of Corporate Ownership in Japan, “ECGI Working Paper Series in
Finance” 2003, no. 20.
[50] D.-S. Cho, D.-H. Lee, S.-J. Ryu,
D.-W. Cho, D.-J. Kim, Comparative Study of Korean and Japanese Industrial Policies
Though Content Analysis of Official Documents, “Hitotsubashi
Journal of Commerce and Management” 1996, no. 31 (1), p. 59-74.
[51] See: S.-H. Chun, Economic
Development, and Tax Policy and Tax System in Korea, “Research
Paper”, Korea Institute of Public Finance, Seoul 2002. For the analysis of the
importance of the R&D during Koreas industrialisation, see: A.H. Amsden,
op.cit.
nr 2(2)2014
[52] B. Cumings, op.cit., p. 2.
[53] Y.
Kobayashi, The Role and Significance of Japanese Industrial Policy: Its
Estimation and Recent Issue, “Economic Journal of Hokkaido University” 1993, no. 22, p. 81.
[54] J.-G. Jeon, Exploring the
Three Varieties of East Asias State-Guided Development Model: Korea, Signapore, and Taiwan, “Studies in Comparative International Development” 1995, no. 30(3),
p. 74.
[55] I. Yamazawa,
Trade Policy and Changes in Japans Trade Structure - With Special
Reference to Lahour- -Intensive Manufactures, “The Developing Economies” 1975, no. 386.
[56] Ch.-H. Nam, The Role of
Trade and Exchange Rate Policy in Korea's Growth, in: Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience, eds. T. Ito, A. Krueger, University of Chicago Press,
Chicago 1995, p. 154.
nr 2(2)2014
[57] K.S. Kim, op.cit., p. 30.
[58] J.-E. Woo, Race to the
Swift: The Role of Finance in Korean Industrialization, Columbia University Press, New York 1991.
[59] M. Noland, op.cit., p. 255.
[60] F. Kimura, Japans Model
of Economic Development: Relevant and Nonrelevant Elements for Developing
Economies, “WIDER Working Paper” 2009, no. 22.
[61] J.S. Mah, Export
Promotion Policies, Export Composition and Economic Development of Korea,
Paper prepared for the Law and Development Institute Inaugural Conference,
Sydney 2010, p. 8.
[62] See: S. Haggard, R.N. Cooper, S.
Collins, Ch. Kim, S.-T. Ro, Macroeconomic Policy and Adjustment in Korea, 1970-1990,
“Harvard Studies in International Development”, Harvard Institute for
International Development, Harvard University Press, Cambridge 1994; Ch.-H.
Nam, op.cit.
nr 2(2)2014
[63] P. Evans, Transferable
Lessons? Re-Examining the Institutional Prerequisites of East Asian Economic
Policies, “Journal of Development Studies” 1998, no.
34(6), p. 82.
[64] M. Beeson, The Rise and
Fall (?) of the Developmental State: The Vicissitudes and Implications of East
Asian Interventionism, in: Developmental
States: Relevancy Redundancy or Reconfiguration?, ed. L. Low, Nova Science Publishers, New York 2004.
[65] T. Mkandawire, Thinking
about Developmental States in Africa, “Cambridge Journal of
Economics” 2001, no. 25 (3), p. 289-313.
nr 2(2)2014
[66] A. Kefale, Narratives
ofDevelopmentalism and Development in Ethiopia: Some Preliminary Explorations, Paper submitted for the 4th European Conference on African
Studies, Uppsala, 15-18 June 2011; A. Desta, Emerging
Challenges in Democratic Developmental State: The Case of Ethiopian Growth and
Transformation.
[67] O. Edigheji, A Democratic
Developmental State in Africa?, “A Concept Paper, Research
Report” 2005, no. 105, Centre for Policy Studies; K. Olayode, Reinventing
the African State: Issues and Challenges for Building a Developmental State,
“African Journal of International Affairs” 2005, no. 8(1-2), p. 23-43.